Hospitals choose quality such that: \[\frac{\partial \pi_{j}}{\partial z_{j}} = \left(\bar{p} - \frac{\partial c_{j}}{\partial q_{j}} \right)\left(\frac{\partial s_{j}}{\partial z_{j}}D + s_{j}\frac{\partial D}{\partial z_{j}} \right) - \frac{\partial c_{j}}{\partial z_{j}}=0\]
Alternative expression for quality: \[z_{j} = \left(\bar{p} - c_{q} \right) \left(\eta_{s} + \eta_{D} \right) \frac{D s_{j}}{c_{z}}\]
Profit given by \(\pi = q(p,z) \times (p-c-d\times z) - F,\) which yields
\[\begin{align*} p &= \frac{\epsilon_{p}}{\epsilon_{p}-1} (c+dz) \\ z &= \frac{\epsilon_{z}}{\epsilon_{z}+1} \frac{p-c}{d} \end{align*}\]
Rewrite in terms of elasticities:
\[\begin{align*} \epsilon_{p} &= \frac{p}{p-c-dz} \\ \epsilon_{z} &= \frac{dz}{p - c - dz} \end{align*}\]
Taking the ratio and solving for \(z\) yields, \[z = \frac{p}{d}\times \frac{\epsilon_{z}}{\epsilon_{p}}.\]
\[z = \frac{p}{d}\times \frac{\epsilon_{z}}{\epsilon_{p}}\]
Dorfman-Steiner condition:
Prediction for competition: Hospitals will compete on whatever matters most to patients.
Gowrisankaran, Nevo, and Town extend the Nash bargaining framework to consider a hospital-insurer negotiation. They propose a two-stage bargaining process:
Bargaining occurs over a base price, not specific to each procedure
In the case of a single hospital system, and denoting hospital \(j\)’s marginal cost for services provided to patients in MCO \(m\) is given by \(mc_{mj}\), the overall profit for hospital \(j\) for a given set of MCO contracts (denoted \(M_{s}\)), is \[\pi_{j}\left(M_{s},\{\vec{p}_{m}\}_{m\in M_{s}} \right)=\sum_{m\in M_{s}} q_{mj}(N_{m},\vec{p}_{m}) \left[p_{mj} - mc_{mj} \right].\]
The authors then derive the Nash bargaining solution as the choice of prices maximizing the exponentiated product of the net value from agreement:
\[\begin{align*} NB^{m,j} \left(p_{mj} | \vec{p}_{m,-j}\right) &= \left(q_{mj}(N_{m},\vec{p}_{m}) \left[p_{mj} - mc_{mj} \right]\right)^{b_{j(m)}} \\ & \times \left(V_{m}(N_{m},\vec{p}_{m})-V_{m}(N_{m,-j},\vec{p}_{m})\right)^{b_{m(j)}}, \end{align*}\]
where \(b_{j(m)}\) is the bargaining weight of hospital \(j\) when facing MCO \(m\), \(b_{m(j)}\) is the bargaining weight of MCO \(m\) when facing hospital \(j\), and \(\vec{p}_{m,-j}\) is the vector of prices for MCO \(m\) and hospitals other than \(j\). We can normalize bargaining weight such that \(b_{j(m)} + b_{m(j)} = 1\).
Taking the natural log, the resulting first order condition yields:
\[\begin{align*} \frac{\partial \ln (NB^{m,s})}{\partial p_{mj}} =& b_{s(m)} \frac{q_{mj} + \frac{\partial q_{mj}}{\partial p_{mj}} \left[p_{mj}-mc_{mj}\right]}{q_{mj}\left[p_{mj}-mc_{mj}\right]} \\ & + b_{m(j)} \frac{\frac{\partial V_{m}}{\partial p_{mj}}}{V_{m}(N_{m},\vec{p}_{m})-V_{m}(N_{m,-j},\vec{p}_{m})} = 0 \end{align*}\]
Simplifying and rewriting, we get: \[p_{mj} - mc_{mj} = -q_{mj} \left(\frac{\partial q_{mj}}{\partial p_{mj}} + q_{mj} \times \frac{b_{m(j)}}{b_{j(m)}} \times \frac{\frac{\partial V_{m}}{\partial p_{mj}}}{\triangle V_{m}} \right)^{-1}\]
Bargaining tends to increase the “effective” price sensitivity and reduce hospital margins relative to standard pricing conditions (but not always)
\[-q_{mj}-\alpha \sum_{i}\sum_{d}\gamma_{id}c_{id}(1-c_{id}) \left(\sum_{k\in N_{m}} p_{mk}s_{ikd} - p_{mj}\right),\]
Lots of subjectivity…
Almost any way you define it, hospital markets are more and more concentrated (less competitive) in recent decades.
Source: Gaynor, Ho, and Town (2015). The Industrial Organization of Health Care Markets. Journal of Economic Literature.
Historical perception of hospital competition as “wasteful” and assumption that more capacity means more (unnecessary) care:
Effects for both “in-market” and “out-of-market” mergers
Every analysis of competition requires some definition of the market. This is complicated in healthcare for several reasons:
Once we have a measure of the market, we’d like to have a quick and easy way to assess competitiveness:
Step 1. Derive ex post utility.
\[\begin{align*} U_{ij} &= \alpha R_{j} + H_{j}'\Gamma X_{i} + \tau_{1} T_{ij} + \tau_{2} T_{ij} X_{i} + \tau_{3} T_{ij} R_{j} - \gamma(Y_{i},Z_{i}) P_{j}(Z_{i}) + \varepsilon_{ij} \\ &= U(H_{j},X_{i},\lambda_{i}) - \gamma(X_{i})P_{j}(Z_{i}) + \varepsilon_{ij}, \end{align*}\]
which yields choice probabilities, \[s_{ij} = s_{j}(G,X_{i},\lambda_{i}) = \frac{\text{exp}(U(H_{j},X_{i},\lambda_{i}))}{\sum_{g\in G}\text{exp}(U(H_{g},X_{i},\lambda_{i}))}.\]
Step 2. Derive utility from access to network, \(G\), with \(U(H_{g},X_{i},\lambda_{i})\) taken as given.
The patient’s expected maximum utility across all hospitals is, \[V(G,X_{i},\lambda_{i}) = \text{E} \left[\max_{g\in G} U(H_{g},X_{i},\lambda_{i}) + \varepsilon_{g} \right] = \text{ln} \left[\sum_{g\in G} \text{exp} (U(H_{g},X_{i},\lambda_{i})) \right].\]
Contribution of hospital \(j\) is then:
\[\begin{align*} \triangle V_{j}(G,X_{i},\lambda_{i}) &= V(G,X_{i},\lambda_{i}) - V(G_{-j},X_{i},\lambda_{i}) \\ &= \text{ln} \left[ \left(\sum_{k\in G_{-j}} \frac{ \text{exp} (U(H_{k},X_{i},\lambda_{i})) }{\sum_{g\in G} \text{exp} (U(H_{g},X_{i},\lambda_{i})) }\right)^{-1} \right] \\ &= \text{ln} \left[ \left(\sum_{k\in G_{-j}} s_{k}(G,X_{i},\lambda_{i})\right)^{-1} \right] \\ &= \text{ln} \left[ \left( 1- s_{j}(G,X_{i},\lambda_{i})\right)^{-1} \right]. \end{align*}\]
Translate into dollar values by weighting by the marginal utility of price \[\triangle \tilde{W}_{j} = \frac{\triangle V_{j}}{\gamma (X_{i})}.\]
Step 3. Estimate ex ante WTP to include hospital \(j\) in patient’s network. (i.e., integrate over all possible health conditions)
\[W_{ij}(G,Y_{i},\lambda_{i}) = \int_{Z} \frac{\delta V_{j}(G,X_{i},\lambda_{i})}{\gamma (X_{i})} f(Z_{i}|Y_{i},\lambda_{i}) dZ_{i}.\]
Further integrating over all patients, \((Y_{i},\lambda_{i})\), yields \[WTP_{j} = N \int_{\lambda} \int_{Z} \int_{Y} \frac{1}{\gamma (X_{i})} \text{ln}\left[\frac{1}{1-s_{j}(G,X_{i},\lambda_{i})} \right]f(Y_{i},Z_{i},\lambda_{i})dY_{i} dZ_{i} d\lambda_{i}.\]
Simplify by calculating WTP for each “micro-market” (e.g., health condition) and taking sum:
\[WTP_{j} = - \sum_{m} N_{m} \text{ln}(1 - s_{mj})\]